Seeing as the hamster will be leaving the City in a couple
of months, I thought I would share some reflections on my short time in the
City / in finance . Rather than a City Boy-esque critique of conspicuous
consumption, the aim of these pieces is to compare my (totally fictitious for
legal reasons) experience with some of the broader critical themes that have
played out in the press of late. I will write in three parts. Part 1 will be
more a technical critique of the system (for my own piece of mind), whilst part
2 will be more along the lines of good ol’ fashioned banker bashing. Part 3
will explore some potential solutions. Read as you desire.
To start with I will need to lay out the key pillars, governing our financial system, which I shall refer to as the “Anglo-Saxon”
system. I want to then evaluate this, through the lense of my experience,
against three criteria namely:
1)
Is the system effective in achieving its aims?
(part 1)
2)
Is the system fair? (part 2)3) Is a career in the city conducive to living the good life? (part 2)
Whilst not a complete set of criteria, these are the
questions that I believe are most pertinent.
The Anglo-Saxon model
of finance
As the things bought with these big cheques are put to use they
earn a return (of smaller cheques) that eventually work their way through the
system back to a bank account, saving scheme or insurance claim.



The key interrelationship here is that Anglo Saxon pillars
one (self-interest) and two (many small companies) mean that the outcomes of
feature three (innovation) will ultimately be useful for the
saving-investment-return system and not be money-making ends in themselves.
Compared to the past
and the developing world, the system is doing alright..
The other context, geography, is also important. Across the
world there are markets that suffer from a patchy and inefficient finance
system. Two examples that come to mind are the Indian economy where excess
wealth often does not find itself in the financial system, but often invested
into (socially useless) gold.
The other is the example of smallholder farmers in Sub-Saharan Africa. NGO’s
such as the One Acre Fund,
have demonstrated that by providing finance, smallholder farmers are able
to buy essential equipment and working capital (seeds, fertiliser) and increase their yields significantly. In his
book, Roger Thurrow describes how without such finance, smallholder farmers may be limited to
cultivating only a quarter of their available land, condemning themselves and
their families to a hunger season every year. Compare this to a financial
system in the UK which, for better or worse, will send you a credit card in the
post that you can sign and use in the same day!
However, enough of the defence. My time in the industry
raised several alarm bells that made me think, despite its successes, there
are some features that tend to lead to perverse outcomes. I break these
into the following categories:
The system is only
as good as its savers, and their horizons
As set out above, the bedrock of the system is individual people’s savings (as opposed to say a trust fund of a nation’s wealth). People often want to deposit their excess wealth in savings accounts to preserve the value of the cash and earn a return. People also want to be able to access that cash should any short term need arises. This is in direct contrast to the investment horizons of big cheques, which will often only earn a return over a long period of time. This creates a tension in the system between the money supplied (short term, risk-averse) and the money demanded (often longer term and risky). Finance theory has two solutions to this problem, namely:
- You can use some short term money (deposits) for long term investments if you assume that people will not try to withdraw their cash en masse (this failure is very much at the centre of most financial crises and there is not enough space in this blog to explore it!)
- A good system will have a variety of ‘savers’, who will place their money according to their own attitude to risk. As a result, you will have a wide pool of money with different time-horizons and risk requirements.
Fine in practice, but in my experience this leaves huge gaps.
In particular, there tends to be a gaping whole in long-term, risky investment.
What I mean by this is that the system is not very good at producing big
cheques for projects or businesses that do no begin to reap rewards for 10 to 30
years and where there is an element of uncertainty attached. Again and again
this means important investment in big long-term useful activity e.g. in upgrading
trains, expanding social housing, backing heavy industry, developing green energy, funding research and
development or investing in preventative healthcare is either not made or
requires considerable help from the state or state-like institutions.
The result of this is in the past has been serious
underinvestment. With the rolling back of the state beginning with Thatcher,
Britain’s private finance back sectors have been slow to invest in several
areas. This article, explores why, for instance, no-one has invested to
upgrade trains in the UK for decades. In my experience, I have seen rolling stock companies backed with this "wrong" type of finance unable to
invest in something society knows is important i.e. the replacement of knackered,
inefficient, unreliable, 40+ year old trains (designed for retirement at age 30). In a damning reflection of the systems failure, I worked on a project to
buy rolling stock which was originally called T'link 2000; the contracts were
signed in 2013, in part due to dithering and ridiculously high levels of risk aversion amongst financing parties.
A particularly fashionable solution to short termism is for
the state to de-risk investments by saying they will effectively guarantee any return
or wear the costs should a project not complete. This is done to try and attract
long-term, low risk money, which to some extent exists through pension funds etc.
Whilst this solution, epitomised by Public Private Partnership (PPP), was
effective at refreshing the UK’s stock of schools and hospitals, it also lead to
a big bonanza for the City during the New Labour era. I will I expand on this in
part 2.
The ‘innovative’
solutions to the above problems are so complex that they either lead to
instability or get captured by those in the know..
Although it was not the part of the city I was involved in,
I believe certain innovations have become so complex, so critical to the system
and understood by so few that any defence of their use has become spurious.
Short selling, default swaps, options and packaged securities were all
more-or-less created to solve the problem of matching up savers who have
different preferences to the returns actually generated by their big cheques. But they have evolved into something else. The
securitisation of US subprime mortgages
that effectively triggered the financial crisis
is a striking example of an innovation that ultimately failed. What’s more, at
the same time as destabilising the system and having little social use, these
innovations were responsible for making a lot of people a lot of money. This is
covered in part 2 of this posting.
High pay = odd incentives
Not only does the Anglo-Saxon system have shortcomings
because there is not enough of the right type of money, there is also not
enough of the right type of people! A big gripe of mine in my time in finance was the entrenched
high level of pay and the knock on impact of this. Before looking at
the merits of a project or the wider impact, I guarantee any finance
institution will first ask how it can pay a partner or director a six figure salary, with annual bonus expectations of 2 to 3
times that amount. I’ve cringed several times when colleagues have joked that ‘"Mr. big shot director" will not get out of bed for any thing less than £50
million’ meaning that unless a project is big enough it will not even be worthy
of attention. This leaves another gaping hole in our finance system and it is
no wonder that banks struggle to lend to small and medium size enterprises.
The problem is that the city has developed to crowd around
big cheques. A big cheque allows people to justify big pay. Say, for instance, you were a lender and you took a 1% upfront fee when making a loan. The natural
pull will be either to (i) make big loans, rather than work through a myriad of
smaller ones (if the time required to make small and big loans is similar) or
(ii) make a series of small loans that require very little work. The result is
that big money (lending to big corporations or projects) or dumb money (lending
to say mortgage applicants based on online applications) are favoured. This
leaves a whole swathe of the economy either:
- ignored (a comparison of the history of my former institution and its current strategy to focus on big established companies is case in point);
- subject to too much attention; or
- subject to mechanistic, "computer-says-no" decision making processes (e.g. US sub-prime mortgages).
Model assumes that we know how to judge performance
Pillar one of the Anglo-Saxon model argues that little regulation is required in finance as Darwinian competition continually weeds out the weakest cogs in the system. One of the key metrics for understanding whether a cog (i.e. an investor) is successful is risk-adjusted return. Put simply, risky investments are expected to earn higher returns. Investors who make risky investments and low returns are deemed to be no good. Conversely, low risk investments that earn excessive returns are expected to be short-lived.
The problem with this is that finance is not like a goods
market where people know if a product is any good or if people are charging too
much. Finance is different in that it is very difficult to identify a bad
product (i.e. an investment that delivers inappropriate risk-adjusted returns) . Even worse people can be deluded for very
long periods of time and these bad products have the potential of
destabilising a whole economy. The following are reasons why this is a feature
of finance:
- Some people may just be lucky. Consider the analogy of an investor going to a roulette table with the strategy of choosing red everytime and re-investing all the money on every bet. Now say they were lucky in winning three bets in a row. In finance this person would regarded as having a good track record and someone who you should bank your money with. However, this does not take away from the fact that the next bet is still 50:50. In my time in the industry, there were several people who rode the wave of the good times (pre 2007) and now remain in the industry (and prosper), despite poor outcomes since, purely because of the ‘experience’ they were able to gather when they were (by luck) deemed to be good investors. These people do earn six figure salaries and large annual bonuses, but will have personally have been involved in investments that returned nothing or lost millions of pounds.
- Financial risk is not really that well
understood as it pre-supposes you understand all future possible outcomes and are
able to assign a probability to each. As we have seen, in this crisis
certain unknown unknowns can completely destabilise the system. Further, even
the stuff we do know may be highly influenced by factors we have little
understanding of e.g. artificially low interest rates or the exuberance of
traders.
That said, some parts of finance have learnt their lesson..
Earlier on my career I did used to get quite frustrated with
the level of red tape in the business, often having to spend hours filling
out various forms for compliance and regulatory purposes. In hindsight, such
regulations are probably the product of reforms that have been fought hard for and for which the finance system (and in my particular experience
private equity and commercial lending) should be proud. Without going into
detail I think the system is very good at
- Corporate Governance – ensuring business are governed in a clear, transparent way
- Anti-Bribery policies
- Environmental, Health & Safety – I have seen investors very active in this place, pushing companies to go above and beyond what is expected of them and fighting entrenched lax cultures (e.g. in Finland or India). In western countries today I would be very surprised if investors allowed their companies to get away with environmentally damaging activities or neglecting safety standards for their workerss
- Applying due diligence and due process – despite some poorer investment decisions seen in the crisis, I have seen people go through very thorough processes (when writing big cheques). This means our system avoids, for instance, the c. 40% bad loan provision that the Chinese development banks had towards the end of the 1990’s.
So, is the system effective?
I still stand by the statement that relative to all historic systmens the anglo-saxon model is decent. However, it does have some sizeable shortfalls namely (i) it ignores vast parts of the economy and (ii) through its complexity and entrenched behaviour, it has the potential to de-stabilise a whole economy. In part 3 of this posting, I will look at possible remedies and see how alternative models e.g. Rhine capitalism and the Nordic model get around these issues.
No comments:
Post a Comment